HomeLoveStartLearnPlayConverseResourcesBlog
    HomeLearnModule 5πŸ‘¨β€πŸ‘©β€πŸ‘§β€πŸ‘¦ Incentivize

    Table of contents

    • πŸ‘¨β€πŸ‘©β€πŸ‘§β€πŸ‘¦ Incentives
    πŸ‘¨β€πŸ‘©β€πŸ‘§β€πŸ‘¦ IncentivesΒΆ

    The best 3 (slack) responses or (PR) improvements to this note will be awarded 50 DAI each.


    Need we say more about why incentives matter?

    PersuasionΒΆ

    What constitutes persuasive language? Words which perform what they say. If an essay about humour is itself funny, then that essay is more likely to convince you about what humour is.

    What happens when your code says, "Transfer 50 DAI to Alice" and executes the transfer of value simultaneously? Well, you can build really persuasive incentives for any kind of economic behaviour. How do we know what behaviour we should incentivize though?

    Q: Code which executes economic action can be used to build what kind of incentives?

    Reveal the answer

    A: Persuasive.

    Didn't remember
    Remembered
    Economics in the computer ageΒΆ

    Here's a new kind of economic essay. What makes it interesting is that with a few lines of Python, Peter Norvig proves a surprising result about wealth inequality. The initial distribution of wealth in the economy doesn’t affect the long-run distribution of wealth nearly as much as the nature of the transactions. His code also suggests that constraining agents to trade only with people geographically near them makes little difference to the final distribution of wealth.

    Results like these challenge your intuition. But instead of those challenges being on the basis of abstract arguments, you can engage his model. If you don’t agree that the initial distribution of wealth doesn’t affect long-run wealth inequality, you can try find a counterexample: an initial distribution which does affect inequality. You can experiment easily, making modifications to a few lines of code, trying to find instances where the initial distribution matters. No matter whether you succeed or fail, you will build a better understanding of the problem.

    Used well, Jupyter notebooks become environments for transformative thought. They’re a new media form, with different possibilities from either essays or code. And that's just a notebook, let alone a smart contract. Such contracts deployed on a shared, global network not only demonstrate new economic insights and ideas, they implement them.

    Programming crowdsΒΆ

    You must think like an engineer about the economic games your contracts incentivize. Ironically, the best place to go looking for clear thinking and research in this domain is neither economics, nor psychology. It is computer game design.

    The reason for this is that contractual economic code on a shared, public ledger actually programs crowd behaviour. Don't get too excited by this, for with great power comes great responsibility - which is why the thinking patterns we outlined at the start of these modules have fundamentally to do with humility. You cannot, as an individual, know what the second and third order effects of such code will be. But you can be deeply aware that such effects exist, and you can use your awareness to inform the intention with which you write and deploy contracts.

    This is software as service. We are all Satoshi.

    Q: In order to implement economic games like responsible engineers, what internal state of mind must we cultivate?

    Reveal the answer

    A: Humility.

    Didn't remember
    Remembered
    Previous
    Module 5
    Next
    πŸ‘‚ Listening